Laden...
â  The virus shock is huge â but the shock absorbers will need time to work: Unlike some direct support measures, key macroeconomic shock absorbers work only with a lag. They can take effect only once we have more clarity about the underlying medical emergency. For markets, confidence and ultimately economic activity to turn up again, we will need clear evidence that the spread of the virus is being held back sufficiently to allow health systems to cope. The near-term risks are heavily tilted to the downside. Italyâs decision last night to extend the Lombardy semi-lockdown to the entire country highlights these risks. Only if and when the shock recedes, possibly in late Q2 2020, can the delayed impact of the absorbers support demand. A rebound once lockdowns are eased will then help.
â  Shock absorber one â targeted liquidity support: Plunging demand and interrupted supply chains can cause severe cash-flow problems for companies. Targeted measures to prevent companies and jobs from falling victim to such squeezes should be a top priority to forestall damaging second-round effects. A number of governments, including those of Italy, Germany and the UK, are now introducing or strengthening such programmes.
â  Shock absorber two â direct labour market support: Targeted support for temporary underemployment on the job can limit the number of dismissals, even in a sharp downturn. Partly due to Germanyâs âKurzarbeitergeldâ subsidy for reduced working hours, German employment fell only slightly despite a record plunge in output in early 2009 (see chart). Germany is now making it easier to access this scheme. Other countries should follow.
â  Shock absorber three â monetary policy: Liquidity injections to relieve financial stress and support bank lending to corporates can limit second-round effects. Rate cuts and assets purchases can limit market routs and stimulate demand once the virus shock has started to fade. After the 50bp Fed cut of 3 March, we expect a serious easing package from the European Central Bank on 12 March, a 50bp Bank of England cut in March and a new Fed cut by 50bp on 18 March, followed by another 25bp Fed move in Q2. If need be, the European Stability Mechanism and the ECB would have the tools to address negative feedback loops between banks and sovereigns.
â  Shock absorber four â fiscal policy: Most advanced countries are easing fiscal policy. We expect the UK to announce a stimulus of c1.0% of GDP at its 11 March budget. Germany looks set to raise its slow-motion stimulus from 0.4% to c0.6% for 2020. The medical emergency gives countries including Italy space to raise spending and offer targeted relief to stricken companies and households. The plunge in most sovereign bond yields lowers financing costs for many economies and enhances the fiscal space of many governments. We also expect the US Congress to set partisan politics aside for once and pass a substantial fiscal package soon.
â  Shock absorber five â the oil price: As in a J-curve, the immediate negative impact of lower oil prices on energy sector investment and corporate bond spreads shapes first market reactions. However, as in 2016, the positive impact on real consumer incomes will be more powerful in the end. Households will have more money to spend once confidence stabilises. A sustained oil price drop by â¬10 per barrel would reduce headline inflation by c0.3ppt within two months across much of Europe, adding to real incomes and spending power by the same magnitude. Lower oil prices also give the central banks more room to ease. That mitigates credit risks. The Fed and other agencies would act decisively if a limited debt shake-out threatened to morph into a big macroeconomic calamity.
Click here for full report and disclosures
Holger Schmieding
Chief Economist
+44 7771 920377
holger.schmieding@berenberg.com
This material is intended as commentary on political, economic or market conditions for institutional investors or market professionals only and does not constitute a financial analysis or a research report as defined by applicable regulation. See the "Disclaimers" section of this report.
The commentary included herein was produced by Joh. Berenberg, Gossler & Co. KG (Berenberg). For sales inquiries, please contact:
Phone: +44 (0)20 3207 7800
Email: berenberg.economics@berenberg.com
BERENBERG
Joh. Berenberg, Gossler & Co. KG
Neuer Jungfernstieg 20
20354 Hamburg
Germany
Registered Office: Hamburg, Germany
Local Court Hamburg HRA 42659
For Berenberg the protection of your data has always been a top priority. Please find information on the processing of personal data here.
Any e-mail message (including any attachment) sent by Berenberg, any of its subsidiaries or any of their employees is strictly confidential and may contain information that is privileged or exempt from disclosure under applicable law. If you have received such message(s) by mistake please notify the sender by return e-mail. We ask you to delete that message (including any attachments) thereafter from your system. Any unauthorised use or dissemination of that message in whole or in part (including any attachment) is strictly prohibited. Please also note that any legally binding representation needs to be signed by two authorised signatories. Therefore we do not send legally binding representations via e-mail. Furthermore we do not accept any legally binding representation and/or instruction(s) via e-mail. In the event of any technical difficulty with any e-mails received from us, please contact the sender or info@berenberg.com. Deutscher disclaimer.
Click here to unsubscribe from these emails.
Laden...
Laden...
© 2024